modi make

By Dilip Abreu, Pranab Bardhan, Maitreesh Ghatak, Ashok Kotwal, Dilip Mookherjee and Debraj Ray

Jagdish Bhagwati and Arvind Panagariya (BP , in short) have argued for phasing out the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act in favour of cash transfers (“Rural Inefficiency Act”, TOI, October 23). They assert that NREGA is an inefficient “instrument of shifting income to the poor”. BP even claim that it costs five rupees to transfer one rupee to NREGA workers.

Their argument: consider a worker who currently earns Rs 80 a day in the private sector but decides to work on NREGA for Rs 130 instead. He or she earns an extra Rs 50, but this costs the government Rs 248: Rs 130 in wages, Rs 56 in material (assuming a material-labour ratio of 30-70), and Rs 62 in leakages (assuming 25% of expenditure is embezzled).

This argument is misleading.

The first concern is whether potential NREGA workers have alternative gainful employment. Often they don’t, as NREGA work is provided mainly in the slack season. This is especially true for women -more than half of all NREGA workers. With involuntary unemployment, the question of “currently earning Rs 80 a day in the private sector” does not arise; so the income gain is Rs 130, not Rs 50.

If, for the sake of argument, workers do currently earn Rs 80, it is only true that the gain for the NREGA worker is Rs 50. However, what matters is the gain, direct and indirect, for all workers. In this scenario, there will typically be a wage increase (though not “by leaps and bounds”, as attributed by BP to mysterious propagandists), which benefits all employed workers. This is possible even when NREGA employment is wholly concentrated in the slack season (if higher slack earnings tighten peak labour supply). Even small increases in the market wage translate into large aggregate benefits, given the size of the labour force under consideration.Only extreme assumptions -unspecified by BP -would yield a net gain as dismally low as they perceive.

Second, BP ignore non-transfer benefits, starting with NREGA assets. Rural roads, soil conservation, flood control, groundwater recharge and land improvement projects may not shine as brightly as the smart cities BP so enthusiastically endorse, but they do contribute to India’s development. A recent study of over 4,000 NREGA assets across Maharashtra, by the Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, found that most of them are valued by local residents. BP assume they are all useless.They also ignore the evidence on other benefits: for instance, empowerment of women who work in large numbers, reduction in distress migration and impact on schooling achievements.

In short, BP’s argument is based on inflating the costs of NREGA and deflating the benefits. This biased accounting spills over to their espousal of cash transfers: how a cash transfer system will identify the poor is glossed over, as is the inherent self-selection advantage of NREGA (clearly only the most needy are willing to do hard manual work). Perhaps BP intend cash transfers to be universal. But then, by their own logic (which counts only transfers to the poor as benefits), there would be enormous leakages in terms of transfers to the well-off.

Shortcomings of NREGA implementation have certainly been reported: these include delays in wage payments, benami payments, unmet work requests and material irregularities. Yet numerous studies based on independent household survey data (reviewed by one of us at http:www.ideasforindia.in) have shown significant benefits in terms of income security for the most vulnerable.NREGA provides employment to some 50 million rural households, affecting the lives of up to 250 million individuals. National Sample Survey data shows a large unmet demand for NREGA employment in all states. When more than 90% of the workforce is informal and lacks access to social security , this is a critical intervention.Leakage rates remain substantial, but they are declining and no higher than in many other subsidy programmes.

We share BP’s concern about “the folly of embracing substantial spending programmes unmatched by revenues”, but not their astonishing inference that “this alone justifies the decision to confine NREGA to 200 poorest districts”. To put matters in perspective, consider estimates by the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy of total “non-merit” subsidies (implicit and explicit, Centre and states) to the better-off in India: about 9% of GDP , over 20 times the expenditure on NREGA (less than 0.4% of GDP). Surely , there are better ways of ensuring fiscal responsibility than to deprive millions of workers of an important (and sometimes crucial) source of livelihood.

We do not claim that all is well with NREGA. The programme needs better design and implementation, not slow suffocation. And certainly the public debate is not well-served by facile attacks uninformed by the facts.

(The authors are professors of economics at Princeton University, University of California Berkeley, London School of Economics, University of British Columbia, Boston University and New York University respectively.)

http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/home/stoi/all-that-matters/Wrong-numbers-Attack-on-NREGA-is-misleading/articleshow/45085301.cms